社会経済史学
Online ISSN : 2423-9283
Print ISSN : 0038-0113
ISSN-L : 0038-0113
51 巻, 1 号
選択された号の論文の6件中1~6を表示しています
  • チャウドゥリ K. N.
    原稿種別: 本文
    1985 年 51 巻 1 号 p. 1-16
    発行日: 1985/06/10
    公開日: 2017/07/08
    ジャーナル オープンアクセス
    This paper argues that the transition from pre-modern trade to post-Industrial Revolution trade in Asia and indeed in the world generally incorporated a fundamental change in its causation. Pre-modern trade was essentially derived from socially-determined demand arising out of cultural habits and interpretations, but of course, the force of demand operated through market forces and relative prices. Nineteenth-century international trade, on the other hand, was founded on the supply and the production side of the world economy. The fundamental changes in the system of economic production based on the application of machinery and the capitalist organisation made movements of industrial raw materials, food stuffs, and even manufactured goods appear as induced effects of the needs of producers to keep production going. In the pre-modern period, the thinking of merchants and others involved in the business of distant trade, was overwhelmingly influenced by demand factors. This is far removed from the present-day situation in which international trade is primarily a function of the relative distribution of technological endowments. In the earlier period, the technology of production had stabilised itself over many centuries and was treated as if it was a constant. The force of change and the opportunity for accumulating wealth came mainly from shifts in demand and an improvement in the institutional arrangements of economic exchange which lowered costs. There is little disagreement among historians that Asia's inter-regional trade underwent a profound change between 1800 and 1900. The transformation touched both the direction and the composision of goods exchanged. The payments mechanism itself gave rise to induced changes and brought into being the famous trian gular commercial relations between India, China, and Britain, which developed into a true multilateral systems of trade and payments mechanism during the second half of the nineteenth century. Imperialism as an economic force fused together with its political manifestations to form the most powerful historical phenomenon of the time.
  • 杉原 薫
    原稿種別: 本文
    1985 年 51 巻 1 号 p. 17-53
    発行日: 1985/06/10
    公開日: 2017/07/08
    ジャーナル オープンアクセス

    During the second half of the nineteenth century most regions of Asia became colonies of Western powers or were forced to open their ports to foreign trade with them through unequal treaties. As a result Asia's trade with the West grew and Asian economies became more integrated into the world market. The annual average rate of growth of Asia's exports to the West during the period of 1883 to 1913 was 3.2 per cent, which was about the same as the rate of growth of world trade. However, there was also a rapid growth of intra-Asian trade. The rate of growth of intra-Asian trade was probably about 5.4 per cent, much higher than that of Asia's growth of trade as a whole. While the development of export economies, exporting primary' products to the West and importing manufactured goods from there, occurred in Africa and Latin America as well as in Asia, the intra-regional trade of this kind did not develop in other non-Western world, at any rate to such a significant degree. In fact many studies on Africa and Latin America have shown the opposite, i. e. the development of the "enclave" economy only linked with the Western "core" countries without giving linkage effects on other parts of the regional economy. Why then was such a regionwide growth made possible only in Asia? I have tried in this paper to illustrate some features of the growth of intra-Asian trade, to discuss the main factors contributing to it, and to point out the direction of a reinterpretation of Asia's response to the Western impact in a comparative perspective. It is clear that the "engine of growth" of intra-Asian trade was the emergence of the modern cotton industry in India and in Japan, as it stimulated the cotton trade on many levels; exports of Indian raw cotton to Japan, exports of Indian and Japanese yarn to China, exports of Japanese cotton manufacture and "sundries" to China etc. Such a growth of cotton trade led to an international specialization on an Asian scale, and opened up new market opportunities for primary producers. Rice producers in South-east Asia were among those who responded to them. Thus there emerged an Asian internatinal division of labour with Japan and India as exporters of manufactured goods and importers of primary products on the one hand, and China and South-east Asia as exporters of primary products and importers of manufactured goods on the other. The nature of intra-Asian trade described above was essentially an "autonomous" one in the sense that most of the production, distribution and consumptinn involved were planned and carried out by Asians themselves. The Western impact, however, was also essential to the growth of intra-Asian trade in some respects. First, the development of export economies in Asia gave a major market for both Asian-made manufactured goods and primary products. Certainly the larger proportions of cotton manufacture and rice were consumed by those engaged in the production of primary products to be exported to the West. To that extent the growth of intra-Asian trade should be interpreted as a result of the final demand linkage effect of Asia's trade with the West. Second, most of the manufactured goods which served for the development of an infrastructure such as railways, ports and cities were imported from the West, without which the intra-Asian trade would have been confined to a centuries-old junk trade. Third, most Asian countries had adopted the gold standard by the end of the nineteenth century so that, while the relative "autonomy" of the silver-using area was lost, capital imports of manufactured goods from the West became easier. Japan's entry to the international gold standard in 1897 confirmed the fact that Asia needed closer contact with the West to develop its own reginal trade network. Most of the literature on Asian economic history have

    (View PDF for the rest of the abstract.)

  • 浜下 武志
    原稿種別: 本文
    1985 年 51 巻 1 号 p. 54-90
    発行日: 1985/06/10
    公開日: 2017/07/08
    ジャーナル オープンアクセス
    In looking into the modern period of Asia, previous studies have generally had two problems as their major research foci. One is the response of Asian countries to European expansion and the other-if it is indeed different-is the general relationships of Asian countries with their Western counter-parts. In other words, the modern history of Asia has been considered from the viewpoint of Western intrusion. Consequently, the history of modern Asia per se has been replaced by descriptions of Euro-Asian relationships. As this view of modern Asian history took the relation between the West and the East beginning with direct intercourse as its starting point, the notion of analyzing Asia's own internal relations and tracing the continuities between premodern and modern Asia was not consciously considered. Furthermore, the study of modern Asia has been valued and even recognized only in terms of the degree of interrelation with Western countries. Such an understanding of modern Asia was based only on a west-centred comparative study and on indirect appraisal. As a result, the internal ties that united the Asian area, an area defined by its own historical characteristics, might be overlooked or even regarded as a residue of an "ancien regime" and, as such, targets to be abolished. From the perspective of economic history, this research lopsidedness seems to be reflected in the study of the so-called "triangular trade", which has been considered to have initiated the modern economic history of Asia. At the risk of oversimplification, we can perhaps say that the general under-standing has been that the trade relations between Great Britain, India and China were established by British cotton capital with a view to using the relation between the three as a medium for developing the Asian market. Looked at from a different aspect, the general understanding seems to be that Asia started its modern economic period by becoming a part of the consuming market for Western products. The inevitable result is that the already existing internal Asian trade relations have been "invisible" and ignored. The issues of traditional intra-Asian trade relations can be classified under the following two headings: (1) The "Junk" trade and its creation of an Asian-wide trade network; (2) Silver circulation and traditional trade settlement using silver as a supporting factor of the Asian trade network. The characteristics of Asian modernization can be clarified by studying these two.
  • 川勝 平太
    原稿種別: 本文
    1985 年 51 巻 1 号 p. 91-125
    発行日: 1985/06/10
    公開日: 2017/07/08
    ジャーナル オープンアクセス
    The present paper is an attempt to investigate into what seems contradictory phenomena observed in nineteenth century Asia: the increasing influx of British cotton manufactured goods into Asia on the one hand, with the development of indigenous cotton textile production in the region on the other. In order to account for this seemingly paradox, some newly found evidence is introduced which shows qualitative differences between British and Asian cotton products, and the following table is presented to demonstrate the fact that the structure of markets for cotton goods differed between India and the Far East, and also particularly the fact that there was virtually little competition between British and Far Eastern cottons. [table] It appeared necessary to devote a whole section (III) to outline how the cotton textile production, which originated in India, spread both west- and eastward to set out the historical background against which the above different types of cottons were encountered in the Asian markets in the later period. This historical account is not ambitious at all, but included in this paper in order to disperse any impression to the reader that those different structures of markets were static. They were, of course, not so, but products of long historical evolution. Some brief mention will also be made of how they underwent changes in the inter-war years.
  • 角山 榮
    原稿種別: 本文
    1985 年 51 巻 1 号 p. 126-140
    発行日: 1985/06/10
    公開日: 2017/07/08
    ジャーナル オープンアクセス
    Rice is a traditional food in Asia and most people in Asia used to rely on rice. Rice, however, has become a world commodity since the middle of the nineteenth century, responsed by the demand of rice increased not only in Europe but also in Asia. This article attempts to show the rapid growth of rice trade in South-East Asia stimulated by the world-wide demand, and also how Japan's rice trade differed from that of the South-East Asian countries. The historical materials and statistics of rice trade used here are mainly Japanese Consular Reports and Japanese official Survey on Rice. Having opened the country to foreign intercourse in 1858, Japan started as an exporter of her such primary products as raw silk, tea, marine products, rice etc. Japan's rice export achieved a peak in 1888-1892. What was the market for Japanese rice at that time? Though there were some fluctuations in different years, the largest market of Japanese rice was Britain followed by Germany till 1889, but Hong Thong appeared to be the largest after 1892. The Japanese Consular Reports from Melbourne suggested that most of the Japanese rice imported to Hong Kong was re-exported to Australia. On the other hand, Siamese rice was largely exported to Singapore and Hong Kong, and to China via Hong Kong. Almost half of Saigon rice went to Hong Kong, and about 20 per cent to Singapore and South Asian countries, though Europe shared only less than 25 per cent. We can say that Japan found its rice markets largely in Europe and Australia, not in South-East Asian countries and China. In this point Japan's rice trade was quite different from that of Siam and French Indo-China. But Japan has soon become a big rice importing country. It were Burma, Korea, French Indo-China and Slam which supplied Japan with vast quantities of rice before the World War I.
  • 原稿種別: 文献目録等
    1985 年 51 巻 1 号 p. 143-148
    発行日: 1985/06/10
    公開日: 2017/07/08
    ジャーナル オープンアクセス
feedback
Top