詳細検索結果
以下の条件での結果を表示する: 検索条件を変更
クエリ検索: "吉冨勝"
20件中 1-20の結果を表示しています
  • 安保 哲夫
    国際経済
    2000年 2000 巻 51 号 48-54
    発行日: 2000/06/20
    公開日: 2010/07/07
    ジャーナル フリー
  • Public Chocie Studies編集委員会
    公共選択の研究
    1986年 1986 巻 8 号 84
    発行日: 1986/12/15
    公開日: 2010/10/14
    ジャーナル フリー
  • *ジン カオ, *近藤 高司, *鈴木 達夫
    日本経営診断学会全国大会予稿集
    2008年 8 巻
    発行日: 2008年
    公開日: 2008/10/29
    会議録・要旨集 フリー
    日本の労働人口は少子・高齢化に急速度で進んでいる,その影響はIT業界の経営にも及び,有能なIT技術者の不足,終身雇用制度の崩壊は人材育成の悪化傾向を示す。IT業界での人材不足問題の解決方法を模索・考察して,日本に特有な団塊世代IT技術者の能力を早急に伝承し,若年層世代の技術者の大量確保・人材育成を考察した。
  • 武藤 恭彦
    国際経済
    1984年 1984 巻 35 号 221-228
    発行日: 1984/09/21
    公開日: 2010/07/07
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 一九八七年と一九二九年
    安保 哲夫
    国際経済
    1989年 1989 巻 40 号 5-19
    発行日: 1989/10/01
    公開日: 2010/07/07
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 建元 正弘
    季刊 理論経済学
    1982年 33 巻 1 号 94-96
    発行日: 1982/05/25
    公開日: 2007/10/18
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 曹 ジン, 近藤 高司, 鈴木 達夫
    日本経営診断学会論集
    2008年 8 巻 221-226
    発行日: 2008年
    公開日: 2009/06/08
    ジャーナル フリー
    東アジア諸国では,企業で即戦力となる高度IT人材の育成戦略が企業や国の責任として確立している。日本におけるITの高度利活用は,欧米諸国に比べ遅れ気味である。いま日本でも産学官が連携し優秀なIT人材を育成する仕組みを作っている。しかし,IT産業改革をリードできる優秀な人材を多数確保する為にもより優れた教育体制を構築すべきである。本研究では,知識社会の先導役であるIT産業の競争力強化を図るため,さらにIT企業の技術者不足を解消するため,東アジア諸国のIT人材育成をわが国と比較検討した。
  • 本多 俊毅
    現代ファイナンス
    2017年 39 巻 31-53
    発行日: 2017/11/30
    公開日: 2017/11/30
    ジャーナル フリー

    日本の公的年金制度は,平成16年に大きな制度変更が行われた.重要な変更点のひとつは年金給付の削減策であり,導入時には公的年金財政の自動安定化装置とされた.しかし,物価スライド特例措置のために給付削減は進まなかった.この特例措置は終了したものの,平成16年改正の給付削減策にも,経済低迷時には削減しないという制限条項が設けられている.この制限条項は,物価や賃金の動向に依存して利得が定まるオプションと考えることができるが,オプション行使時に公的年金財政に与える影響は複雑である.本稿では公的年金の財政収支をモデル化したうえで,給付削減の延期によって生じた影響を試算した.試算によると,平成16年改正時の「基準ケース」から実績値が乖離し,さらに給付削減が延期されことによって,100兆円の年金積立金に対する年間の運用収益率で言うと5%程度の影響があったことが示唆された.

  • 韓国財閥の生き残り戦略
    高 龍秀
    アジア研究
    2008年 54 巻 2 号 71-88
    発行日: 2008/04/30
    公開日: 2014/09/15
    ジャーナル フリー
    This article explores how financial and corporate reform has been achieved in Korea in the aftermath of the Asian financial crisis. In the financial sector remarkable reforms were achieved for several years after the crisis. First, to reduce a huge volume of bad debt in the banking sector the government injected a total of 155. 3 trillion won of public funds by the end of 2001. As a result of this action, the non-performing loan ratio of the banking sector fell from 12. 9% at the end of 1999 to 1. 9% in 2004. Second, some bank mergers and restructuring of financial institutions through financial holding companies has been accomplished.
    There are some arguments about how the Korean financial system should be developed. Some analysts have urged that the Korean financial system should evolve from a bank-based financial system to a capital market-based financial system. However, the underdevelopment of Korea’s capital market and problems related to transparency make such an evolution to a capital market based financial system difficult.
    In the corporate sector, chaebols had lowered their debt-to-equity ratios to 200% by 1999, according to Korean government requirements. The government also required chaebols to overcome the problem of overdiversification. Chaebols exchanged some specific businesses on a large scale. Business consolidation through this type of deal had been proceeding since 1998.
    Among the five largest chaebols, the LG Group started to restructure its group companies under the holding company system in 2001, and the SK Group began to introduce the holding company system in 2007. However, citizens’ groups monitoring the chaebols and state prosecutors have brought some lawsuits against the five largest chaebols. To elucidate these problems, drastic reform of the corporate governance structure of the chaebols is a key issue still to be addressed.
  • 小宮 隆太郎
    季刊 理論経済学
    1984年 35 巻 1 号 1-20
    発行日: 1984/05/24
    公開日: 2007/10/18
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 構造改革の進捗と含意
    深川 由起子
    アジア研究
    2008年 54 巻 2 号 3-10
    発行日: 2008/04/30
    公開日: 2014/09/15
    ジャーナル フリー
    A decade of reform in East Asia has witnessed successful progress in financial restructuring, which has enabled the recent robust growth. However, the real reform needed to achieve a disciplined financial system will require much more time and more intensive efforts, sustained by both mature market functions and efficient banking intermediaries. The East Asian experience so far has proved that a mere shift from bank lending to a corporate finance market did not automatically improve the governance of family-owned and -controlled firms. More stringent rules for empowering minority equity-holders and open access to information may add inconsistent disincentives to list firms, while bond issuance may not be able to offer appropriate financial support for certain types of businesses, if the information costs are included. The banking sector needs more sophistication, especially for supporting small and medium-sized enterprises. Meanwhile, enhancement of financial supervision has become an additional urgent agenda, along with the soaring number of cross-border transactions, often supported by foreign financial institutes with their advanced technologies. After the first round for financial restructuring, the reform in East Asia has entered a new phase: this needs to consist of a more comprehensive approach and speedy implementation of the policy agenda, without indulging in complacency.
  • 岩崎 祐子
    四日市大学論集
    2007年 19 巻 2 号 115-127
    発行日: 2007/03/01
    公開日: 2019/12/01
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 阿部 斉
    年報政治学
    1981年 32 巻 61-80
    発行日: 1982/10/08
    公開日: 2009/12/21
    ジャーナル フリー
  • タイ・マレーシアを観察事例に
    三重野 文晴
    アジア研究
    2008年 54 巻 2 号 11-32
    発行日: 2008/04/30
    公開日: 2014/09/15
    ジャーナル フリー
    This paper critically reviews the conventional discussion on the financial system in Southeast Asia. Discussion of the financial crisis in 1997 has usually stressed, as a way forward, the enhancement of corporate governance, overcoming excess debt finance, and a shift to market based financial methods such as equity and bond markets. By showing numerical evidence for the cases of Thailand and Malaysia, this paper challenges these conventional views from the perspective of the relationship in the region between the financial and industrial sectors.
    Considering the early emergence of the financial sector in Southeast Asia and the relatively delayed industrialization of the region, bank lending to the manufacturing sector is a relatively recent practice. The foreign-capital-led industrialization after the mid-1985s created a further serious cleavage between these sectors. Examination of recent micro-financial data for firms since the early 1990s shows that the debt ratio and the bank borrowing ratio in the major firms in Thailand and Malaysia was surprisingly low, and that these figures neither increased during the early 1990s when crisis was creeping, nor changed after the crisis.
    Ten years on from the crisis, the economy of the region has recovered, a process led mainly by the growth of the manufacturing sector, whilst the financial sector remains stagnated. In spite of the efforts of governments and international organizations, careful empirical observation indicates that the shift in the financial systems towards a market-based approach, such as equity or bond markets, is still in progress.
    The financial system and the corporate finance structure are generally prescribed by the structure of the manufacturing sectors that constitute the demand side of the fund. The unexpectedly slow development of the market-based financial system, in spite of the efforts of the authorities, could mean that the demand for funds through the organized market is still scare in major industries such as export manufacturing.
    In the long run, a change in the financial system and in corporate finance would be brought about by a change in the manufacturing sector, while policy reform in the financial system should remain circumspect. Considering the still inactive financial intermediation of the commercial banks, it is necessary to pursue a balanced recovery of the financial system, instead of a one-sided emphasis on a market-based shift.
  • ―世界金融危機との関連で―
    高橋 和也
    日本EU学会年報
    2012年 2012 巻 32 号 178-201
    発行日: 2012/06/10
    公開日: 2014/06/10
    ジャーナル フリー
    In the aftermath of the Lehman Brothers’ fall, not only the leading countries of the EU but also the new member states (NMS) were facing challenges from economic recession. During the crisis, because of the strong financial inter-linkage relationships among the European Countries, there was concern whether the western European nations would be infected by the financial crisis occurring in some of the NMS. However, even the Baltic countries, which were the most severely affected by the crisis, did not plunge into the situation as did some of the East Asian countries which had experienced a similar crisis in 1997.
    The aim of this paper is to examine that why the policies implemented by the NMS succeeded in overcoming the crisis. The author particularly verifies the characteristics of the banking sectors in the NMS and the policy responses of euro-pegged countries both before and during the crisis. The data that are referenced in this paper are from the BIS, multinational bank statistics, Eurostat, and national central banks.
    On the aspect of the banking sectors, it should be the noted that the liquidity of local subsidiaries was preserved. Since the 1990s, some multinational banks which are called “common lenders” had expanded into the NMS and became those countries’ major banks. At the same time, on the background of the EU’s integration, these banks had also provided retail banking services over a long term. Furthermore, on the basis of the Vienna Initiative, the foreign parent banks, the authorities of home-host countries, and the international financial institutions had participated in multiple lending during the crisis.
    On the aspect of policy responses, what is important is that the fixed exchange rate system was maintained. Depending on the implementation of internal economic adjustments, such as reduction in wages and fiscal restraint, the international competitiveness of exports was restored external debt was also kept at a steady level.
    In the near future, it is necessary to examine whether the dominant oligopoly of multinational banks will maintain the stability and robustness of the banking sectors and the within the area of NMS. At least, from the case of the current crisis, it is obvious that the dominant oligopoly of multinational banks can avoid rapid and massive capital outflows, and the contagion of crisis.
  • 小西 鉄
    アジア研究
    2016年 62 巻 2 号 1-17
    発行日: 2016/04/30
    公開日: 2016/05/17
    ジャーナル フリー
    According to the empirical study by Leuz and Oberholzer-Gee 2006, there is a trade-off between political connections and foreign financing for well-connected firms. Such a dualistic trade-off, however, does not take into consideration the dynamics of a company’s internal structure. This paper takes the case of the Bakrie Group, one of Indonesia’s most powerful business groups, to investigate how such dynamics also influence a firm’s behavior.
    Since its foundation in 1942, the Bakrie Group has grown as a prominent indigenous, or Pribumi, business group, developing businesses in wide range of sectors such as steel and mineral resources under Suharto’s authoritarian regime. After the Group reorganized enormous debts caused by the Asian Economic Crisis in 1997–98, the founder’s eldest son, Aburizal Bakrie, emerged on the Indonesian political stage, and with his political support the Bakrie Group experienced rapid growth. The Bakrie family has continued to dominate the Group’s management, making sure that the “independent” commissioners mandated by corporate governance reform in 1999 were in fact Bakrie supporters.
    After the Global Financial Crisis of 2008, the politically connected group co-founded an international coal mining investment company, Bumi Plc., with Nathaniel Rothschild, a British financial tycoon, and listed it on the London Stock Exchange (LSE), which requires a high standard of corporate governance. This effort was led by a team of professional management personnel within the company in an attempt to improve the Group’s governance. But, after listing on the LSE, the Bakrie family, using financial means, exploited minority shareholders within Bumi Plc. and withdrew from the new LSE-listed company using their business connections. Those shareholders—businesses that shared common interests with the Bakries—clearly impeded accurate corporate governance procedures. The case therefore illustrates that political connections and international finance are not always in a trade-off but, depending on the dynamics within a business group, can be compatible.
    After observing the conflict within the Bakrie Group, a technocratic minister in the government suggested revising Indonesia’s corporate governance standards, admitting there had been a “government failure” and urging more pressure for reform. Introducing more strict regulations to screen each independent commissioner is therefore needed.
  • 大野 健一
    国際経済
    2000年 2000 巻 51 号 26-44
    発行日: 2000/06/20
    公開日: 2010/07/07
    ジャーナル フリー
    Less developed and transitional economies are under increasing pressure to open up and conform to “global standards.” However, today's latecomers often lack basic conditions to generate market economies and compete effectively in the world economy. Commerce and industry are seriously underdeveloped and governments are incapable of assisting private activities or coping with external shocks. The gap between the required level of institutional preparedness and the dismal reality of today's latecomer countries has widened. As a result, many latecomers begin to integrate without adequate preparations and face severe macroeconomic and social crises.For illustration, Vietnam's inconsistent commitment to free trade and Central Asia's response to the Russian crisis are reviewed. To permit step-by-step integration, there should be multiple rules for globalization depending on initial conditions and policy capability.Furthermore, major exchange rates and international finance must be stabilized before encouraging the latecomers to participate in the world economy.
  • 足代 訓史
    大阪経大論集
    2016年 66 巻 5 号 177-
    発行日: 2016年
    公開日: 2018/02/15
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 川波 洋一
    経済学史学会年報
    1999年 37 巻 37 号 14-27
    発行日: 1999年
    公開日: 2010/08/05
    ジャーナル フリー
    The theoretically effective range of K. Marx's credit theory is examined in this paper by comparing periodic financial crises in the 19th century to contemporary financial crisis. In his analysis of the 19th century financial crises, Marx not only criticized the existing monetary theory but assimilated its effectiveness, interpreting the financial crisis as a contradiction between the real economy and the monetary economy.
    The 20th century exhibits several new aspects of financial crisis such as the expansion and implosion of the stock market during the 1920s and the 1930s, frequent occurrences of financial crisis in the post-war U. S. economy, and the international financial crisis during the 1990s. The new aspects of the contemporary financial system, such as the development of securities market, adoption of a managed currency system, etc., emphasize the requirement for a new theory of financial crisis.
    However, given that Marx's credit theory, which declared the internal relationship between accumulation of real capital and the movement of financial transactions, is an effective base for analysis, this paper concludes that the contemporary financial crisis is within the range of effectiveness of Marx's credit theory.
  • 布田 功治
    歴史と経済
    2008年 50 巻 2 号 32-48
    発行日: 2008/01/30
    公開日: 2017/08/30
    ジャーナル フリー
    Much literature exists concerning the causes for the Asian financial crisis, organized around the axes of actual and apparent reasons. However most of these causal analyses are flawed by being based on the very assumptions about policy approaches which they are attempting to justify. In this paper, aside from the suitability of policy approaches, we analyze the root causes of the financial crisis by examining what form of linkage existed between the flow of international short term funds and the Thai financial system, and establish how this brought about the process from economic bubble to financial crisis. The main findings of our analysis are as follows. First, the main causes of the real estate bubble were speculative investment by foreign investors via non-resident baht accounts and speculative financing by finance companies which were subsidiaries of local commercial banks. Second, the intensive inflow of foreign short-term capital clearly contributed to heavy industrialization and rapidly transformed domestic financial markets. Therefore, the Bank of Thailand (BOT) could not quickly impose an effective credit squeeze. Consequently, the financial system changed to one where financial institutions had huge amounts of bad debt, and a liquidity crisis arose from the rapid flight of huge foreign short-term capital when the bubble economy burst. The structural change itself was the essential cause of the currency crisis in Thailand. Finally, one of the main reasons why the crisis became so serious was that BOT could not manage the exchange rate policy on the basis of the correct information about the international financial situation due to the deterioration of internal communication after the bubble burst. Through our analysis we show that the reactions of the domestic entities played an important role indeed in both the development phase and the crisis one, although international factors and path-dependency in the Thai financial system heavily affected the domestic economy.
feedback
Top