詳細検索結果
以下の条件での結果を表示する: 検索条件を変更
クエリ検索: "歴史的制度主義"
13件中 1-13の結果を表示しています
  • ―域内市場統合を事例に―
    井上 淳
    人間生活文化研究
    2018年 2018 巻 28 号 708-720
    発行日: 2018/01/01
    公開日: 2019/07/26
    ジャーナル フリー

     本論文は,既にEU研究に適用されながらもその問題点が指摘されてきた

    歴史的制度主義
    をEU(European Union)研究に活用することができるようにするために,
    歴史的制度主義
    アプローチの操作,修正を試みるものである.

     それまで停滞していたEU統合が1980年代半ばの域内市場統合計画によって息を吹き返すと,EUに対する理論的アプローチが発展した.

    歴史的制度主義
    はそのうちのひとつであり,EU諸機関が時間の経過とともに加盟国政府に影響を与えて,加盟国政府にさらなる制度化を選択させると主張してきた.しかしながら
    歴史的制度主義
    は,政府の国益や選好に関わる前提を競合理論であるリベラル政府間主義と共有したため,議論の上で大きな制約を抱えることになった.本論文はその制約を明らかにしたうえで,EU研究に適合するように
    歴史的制度主義
    を操作,修正する.

     新たに操作を加えた

    歴史的制度主義
    は,加盟国による制度的選択が自国では解決することができない課題の「欧州的(集合的)解決」であること,それゆえに当該制度選択がゆくゆくは加盟国を拘束することを明らかにする.このような理解は,EU研究における
    歴史的制度主義
    に向けられてきた学術的批判にこたえてその問題点を克服するとともに,たとえばユーロ危機の顛末のように一度統合が停滞した後に再統合が進む理由やメカニズムを明らかにする可能性がある.

  • ―統合の漸進を説明するアプローチの探求―
    井上 淳
    日本EU学会年報
    2020年 2020 巻 40 号 156-174
    発行日: 2020/05/30
    公開日: 2022/05/30
    ジャーナル フリー

     The Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) has experienced both stagnation and progress, in other words, stop and go, since the original plan was launched in the 1960s. After the financial and fiscal crisis, the EU has declared to move towards a genuine economic and monetary union and has launched a plan for completing EMU. This paper attempts to explain why and how the EMU has been gradually developed.

     While the EU and its member states tackled the financial, fiscal and economic crisis, the EU began to address the shortcomings of the EMU and launched a plan to complete a genuine EMU. Scholars attempt to analyze such institutional development/improvement through various theoretical approaches, such as liberal intergovernmentalism, neofunctionalism, supranationalism, historical institutionalism and “Failing Forward” approach. This paper overviews understandings and analysis that are developed by such theoretical arguments, and argues that such theoretical approaches fail to grasp a dynamism towards further economic and monetary union because they ignore an international factor that pushes/drives member states and the EU towards integration. Followed by the argument, this paper also exhibits how we understand and analyze the relaunch of the plan for completing EMU by considering an international factor.

     Taking account of international factor helps us understand why the EU had experienced several crisis since its launch of the original plan for the economic and monetary union in the 1960s, and understand why the member states accept the gradual monetary cooperation through the 1980s, the start of the euro, and the relaunch of the plan for completing EMU after the crisis: The EU and its member states usually suggest integration projects in order to mediate exogenous financial and economic shocks; but, they cannot achieve complete agreements for integration due to diverged national interests and preferences; such “incompleteness” of the integration triggers financial speculation and crisis; and member states come to accept the initial plan for integration and a new plan for further integration is launched and implemented. European integration alternates between crisis/stagnation and progress, but gradually moves toward a further and more complete integration.

  • 坂口 謙一
    教育学研究
    2023年 90 巻 1 号 213-214
    発行日: 2023年
    公開日: 2023/06/20
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 西平 直
    教育学研究
    2023年 90 巻 1 号 212-213
    発行日: 2023年
    公開日: 2023/06/20
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 三浦 聡
    国際政治
    1997年 1997 巻 115 号 211-214
    発行日: 1997/05/17
    公開日: 2010/09/01
    ジャーナル フリー
  • ―ASEANとECOWASの比較検証―
    古賀 慶
    国際政治
    2017年 2017 巻 189 号 189_161-189_176
    発行日: 2017/10/23
    公開日: 2018/12/19
    ジャーナル フリー

    Regional security institutions are founded on security systems, such as cooperative security, collective self-defense, and collective security, which play an important role in ensuring member states’ survival in an anarchic international environment. However, such a materialist perspective tells only a partial story about the roles of regional security institutions; these entities also help to define member states’ cognitive template of regional security. Given the concepts of “region” and “security” are both socially constructed, “regional security” is the concept that is ultimately defined and redefined by the group of states, and thus inter-state regional security institutions play an imperative role in that process.

    How do regional security institutions shape the concept of regional security? The most relevant theoretical framework to answer this question is the Copenhagen School’s “securitization” theory. It offers analytical insights in understanding the social construction process of regional security by emphasizing important factors such as speech acts, audience acceptance, and extraordinary measures. Nevertheless, its recent research focus has deviated from inter-state relations and regional security institutions, and the question has been left unanswered.

    In this context, this article, employing a synthesized analytical framework of securitization theory and an agent-centered historical institutionalism, argues that regional security institutions become a “securitization” tool for member states by providing them a staged process to collectively define their own regional security. Specifically, this article proposes a two-stage hypothesis. First, the member states’ perception of a change in the regional distribution of power triggers the securitization process. Second, the securitization process will be completed if member states accept a new threat perception by a securitizing actor and conduct extraordinary measures to deal with the threat. These measures can be conducted only when the existing institutional function cannot manage the new threats. After this cognitive template of regional security is consolidated within the institution, it begins to constrain member states’ strategic thinking and choices.

    To test the hypotheses, this article conducts a comparative case study with the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN)—in the process of establishing the ASEAN Regional Forum in 1994—and the Economic Community of West African States (ECOWAS)—in the process of establishing the protocol relating to the mechanism for conflict prevention, management, resolution, peace-keeping and security.

    The basic findings are three-fold. First, member states’ perception of a change in the regional distribution of power mattered in setting off the securitization process. Second, member states’ agreement with new security threats and extraordinary measures are imperative to complete the securitization process, but a securitization actor can be varied in at each step of the process. Third, historically embedded norms of the regional security institutions should be taken seriously as it narrows the range of strategic choices on extraordinary measures. Despite a lack of sufficient number of case studies, the ASEAN and ECOWAS cases revealed that the complex securitization processes through regional security institutions created and recreated a cognitive template of regional security, which framed their security perspectives.

  • 滝田 毅
    国際政治
    1997年 1997 巻 115 号 209-211
    発行日: 1997/05/17
    公開日: 2010/09/01
    ジャーナル フリー
  • コンディショナリティを題材にして
    山本 直
    日本EU学会年報
    2002年 2002 巻 22 号 56-77,353
    発行日: 2002/09/30
    公開日: 2010/05/21
    ジャーナル フリー
    The European Union has regarded the concept of “democratic principles” as important, which includes human rights, democracy and the rule of law. The purpose of this article is to examine the implication of these principles from the point of view of political conditionality.
    The typical form of the EU conditionality was the inclusion of “essential element clause” and so-called “non-compliance clause” in some agreements between the European Community and the third countries. The formulation of conditionality in this line has developed after the mid-1990's. First, these two clauses were more universally included. Second, the concept of “good governance” has been linked with the non- compliance clause in the new agreement with the African, Caribbean and Pacific states (ACPs). Third, various external assistant programmes under the Community have become conditional.
    In parallel with these trends, the EU has become a global actor in the field of democratic principles. Acceptance of qualified majority voting in the internal procedure of the Community made the non-compliance clause more applicable. This led unific sanctions at EU level in the case of some ACP countries. On the relation to neighboring countries, the strict political conditions have been established, especially in the context of enlargement policy toward Central and Eastern European Countries (CEECs). In addition, the sharing of image of the democratic principles among the Member States through some effort to define them shall increase the actorness of the EU.
    While the conditionality toward the third countries has been strengthened, there is any possibility of “internal” conditionality for the Member States. It seems unclear whether suspension clause of Article 7 TEU introduced by the Amsterdam Treaty is applicable, although new Article 7 (1) TEU by the Nice Treaty will provide some opportunity that EU concludes a risk of breach by a Member State of democratic principles.
    The powers which relate to the conditionality have been transfered from the Member States to the EC/EU level not only in the foreign policy but also in the internal one.
  • 国際政治理論の再構築
    三浦 聡
    国際政治
    2000年 2000 巻 124 号 27-44,L7
    発行日: 2000/05/12
    公開日: 2010/09/01
    ジャーナル フリー
    The last quarter century has witnessed a rising scholarly interest in international institutions. Various reviews of the study have identified several schools of thought. Popular among them is a variable-focused typology: power, interests, and ideas, which in turn produces a neorealism-neoliberalism-constructivism trilogy. Also widely accepted is a distinction based on ontology, epistemology, and methodology, the schism of which is between rationalism and constructivism.
    While building on these works, I pose different questions: How can we conceive of actions and institutions, and how are we to characterize and explore the relationship between them? I would argue that we can answer them in three ways, namely, instrumental, deliberative, and cognitive approaches to international institutions. Appropriating insights of “new institutionalisms” in social sciences, I develop these approaches by explicating three faces of concepts such as rationality, interaction, communication, decision-making procedures, compliance, interests, and ideas.
    Relying upon the logic of consequentiality, instrumentalists focus on actors' calculation and ask how institutions intervene in the process. Actors live under uncertainty so that exchange of private information becomes an important aspect of strategic interaction. They regard institutions as various types of information and as procedures for aggregating various interests. Institutions are only one among many instruments, and actors utilize them as long as they serve their own interests.
    The deliberative approach adopts the logic of appropriateness and argues that actors match their choices not with expected consequences but with situations they find themselves in. Actors live in a world of multiple and potentially conflicting roles and rules. Appropriateness of actions, therefore, can be contested so that common standards need to be established in the process of deliberation. Consensus constitutes the basis of communicative action. Actors can change their conception of appropriateness—norms and rules—while transforming their own conception of interests and identities through socialization. Institutions construct the practice of deliberation, serve as reasons for action, and situate deliberation within the overall decision-making process.
    Cognitivists, with the logic of orthodoxy, explore how actors perceive the world as they know it, and argue that institutions make social cognition possible. Actors live under an ambiguous world. As templates for cognition, schema, scripts, frames, and symbols enable actors to divide the world into many components, to categorize and classify themselves to formulate their identities, and to make the world meaningful. Actors can strategically appropriate these templates from the “cultural toolkit” and construct historical narratives, through which they transform the tools themselves.
    I conclude with considering some implications of this typology for the furure of theories of international institutions. I propose that we should view rationality as “embedded, ” and inquire conditions under which a particular mode of rationality is dominant. Also, I suggest a need for elaborating and expanding the “theoretical toolkit” presented herein.
  • 井上 淳
    人間生活文化研究
    2020年 2020 巻 30 号 444-456
    発行日: 2020/01/01
    公開日: 2020/09/12
    ジャーナル フリー

     ギリシャに端を発する財政,債務危機で一部では崩壊まで懸念されたユーロだったが,現在は「真の経済通貨同盟へ」の標語のもと,それまで取り組まれてこなかった財政同盟や銀行同盟に向けた取り組みすら進んでいる.EUを分析する理論研究は,それぞれがそうした動向に対する説明能力をもつことを示すために,様々な論考を展開している.本論文は,そのうち,EU理論研究の一大学派を形成しておりEU統合を説明する「ベースライン」だと自らを位置づけているリベラル政府間主義(Liberal Intergovernmentalism)を取り上げ,その説明力を検証する.

     リベラル政府間主義は,危機後の取り組みがEU内の債権者であるドイツの国益,選好を反映したものであると議論している.ただ,多くの加盟国が参加する制度にかかる選択が特定加盟国のプロフィールで説明されるという結論は,リベラル政府間主義の特徴である選好形成,政府間交渉,制度選択という3段階のモデルを必要としない説明になりかねない.ドイツの意見が,リベラル政府間主義のいう「トランスアクション・コストが下がる」ものだと受け入れられた理由や背景を説明する必要がある.また,欧州中央銀行による国債買い入れ(OMT)決定のように,危機後の対策の全てがドイツの意見の反映ではない.こうしたリベラル政府間主義に見られる説明不足がその静的かつ短期の視座に起因するのであれば,考慮しなければならない問題である.

     そこで本論文は,経済通貨同盟の提案から今日に至るまでのEUの取り組みを概観した.歴代の経済通貨同盟に関する取り組みは,特定加盟国の国益の反映ではなく,その都度の制度選択は完全な解決でもなかった.経済通貨同盟には,経済や金融面でEUをリードしているドイツよりも,ドイツ・マルクを抑えて対称的な通貨関係を希求するフランスが積極的になっていた.ただ,その制度的なデザインは,フランスの選好,国益通りにはならなかった.それはドイツとて同じであり,各国の国益はそれぞれ部分的にしか反映・採用されていなかったのである.

     そのうえ,これまでのスネーク,欧州通貨制度,ユーロといった諸制度はいずれも「部分的」な解決,つまり未完成のまま徐々に進んできた.リベラル政府間主義は,この「部分的」あるいは「漸進的」にしか統合が行われていない事実,そしてその部分的な統合では各国の国益が単線的に反映されている訳ではないことを捉えなおすべきである.

     初期の経済通貨同盟を実施する直前にこれが破綻したのも,フランスがスネーク(フロート)を離脱したのも,欧州通貨制度が当初不安定だったが1980年代に安定に転じたのも,ドラギ欧州中央銀行総裁がOMT決定にあたって意識したのも,いずれもドイツの通貨や経済政策を評価し,フランス(や危機後はギリシャなど)の通貨や経済評価を懸念する国際金融市場・投機の存在が鍵になっている.加盟国やEUの取り組みを評価する存在がいたからこそ,「部分的」に進められた統合がそれでよしとされることはなく次の危機を招き,加盟国がそれに取り組むことが求められた可能性がある.つまり,統合の進展を説明する際に,加盟国やEU(制度)だけでは説明できない何かを説明要因に加えねばならない可能性がある.今後の研究課題としたい.

  • 河野 勝
    年報政治学
    1999年 50 巻 181-203
    発行日: 1999/12/17
    公開日: 2009/12/21
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 植村 博恭
    季刊経済理論
    2015年 52 巻 1 号 4-21
    発行日: 2015/04/20
    公開日: 2017/04/25
    ジャーナル フリー
    In order to reconstruct the economic theory, we should develop our study on the basis of existing achievements with an intentionally refreshed methodological approach. We have developed "the institutional analysis of socio-economic systems" which integrates the regulation theory, the Post-Keynesian theory and the Radical Economics theory. We have also developed collaborative researches with the various economics of institutions and evolution, and have published books such as the Japanese version of S. Bowles's Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions and Evolution as well as R. Boyer, H. Uemura, and A. Isogai (eds.) Diversity and Transformations of Asian Capitalisms. The aim of this paper is to investigate how we can reconstruct the economic theory, surveying and assessing the results of our collaborative researches from the theoretical point of view. We especially focus on following points. First, the methodology of this theoretical investigation is proposed, while referring to E. Sugimoto'concept of "modern economics" to emphasize the importance of productive academic discussion. Furthermore, it is pointed out that productive discussions have not been promoted due to the dominance of "the Neo-Classical paradigm". Second, after investigating the basic assumptions of the Neo-Classical paradigm, the academic significance and intrinsic theoretical problems of Marx and Keynes are considered, and it is shown how the Post-Marxian and the Post-Keynesian have tried to overcome their problems. Third, based on the recent development of the economics of institutions and evolution, we show our own research agendas on following subjects: mutually determining relations between institutions/macro processes and the behaviors of agents, meso-level coordinating mechanisms, relationships between the financial system and wage-labor nexus, the institutional varieties of capitalism. Fourth, the recent studies of price and wage determination, the financial system and international trade in contemporary capitalism are assessed thoroughly, and the new achievements of researches by the regulation theory and the contemporary Classical trade theory are studied to reconstruct the economic theory.
  • ジョン・クレイトン・キャンベル
    社会科学研究
    2009年 60 巻 2 号 249-277
    発行日: 2009/02/03
    公開日: 2021/02/09
    ジャーナル オープンアクセス
feedback
Top