詳細検索結果
以下の条件での結果を表示する: 検索条件を変更
クエリ検索: "田中辰雄" 経済学者
8件中 1-8の結果を表示しています
  • 合意形成の可能性とコミュニケーション
    深谷 昌弘
    公共選択の研究
    1988年 1988 巻 11 号 13-23
    発行日: 1988/05/20
    公開日: 2010/10/14
    ジャーナル フリー
    Political decision making was the exclusive subject of political science and remained exogenous in the analitical framework of economics. However, the recent development of public economics has changed the situation. The social choice approach deals with collective decision making procedures such as the voting mechanism. The public choice approach regards a political decision as a result of rational behaviors of various agents taking part in the political process. These approaches are principal components of public economics, and a political decision is an endogenous variable for both to solve. This seems one of the distinctive features of public economics.
    These attempts to extend the application area of economics beyond the market mechanism to the political process have brought out many meaningful contributions. However, these expansional efforts in economics would come to the limit as long as we stick to the conventional framework of economics, wherein the utility function of each unit is presumed to be given and to remain unchanged. This presupposition prevents economics from handling the consensus formation in the political process.
    The democratic political process has two stages. One is the stage of decision making or the voting stage. The other is the stage of consensus formation, preceding the voting stage. The latter is a communication process, in which the cognitive system of each decision unit should be supposed to have some sort of possibility of transformation. If there is no room for any transformation, a consensus is no more than another name for a very special situation where all members have the same political opinion by accident.
    The cognitive system of a person is considered to be a system of accumulated informations and to keep self-organizing in the flow of information. We examine, in this paper, the natures and the limits of the economics of the political process from the viewpoint of communication and consensus.
  • oractikaによる追試とトレース
    高橋 伸夫, 大川 洋史, 稲水 伸行
    赤門マネジメント・レビュー
    2009年 8 巻 8 号 433-462
    発行日: 2009/08/25
    公開日: 2018/02/26
    ジャーナル フリー

    高橋伸夫 (1997) の未来傾斜型システムの仮説について追試を行うとともに、特に、組織変革を成功させたX社を毎年度1回ペースで5回にわたって全数調査したデータから各種指標の推移を求めてX社をトレースし、組織としての曲がり角を乗り切った様子を分析し、組織の「コーナリング」の技術について考える。

  • 大森 信
    組織科学
    2015年 48 巻 3 号 29-40
    発行日: 2015/03/20
    公開日: 2015/06/19
    ジャーナル フリー
    本論文の目的は,Strategy as Practice ならびにプラクティス・ターンの観点から戦略,組織,実践の関係性を検討することである.また検討を踏まえ,戦略論ならびに組織論の課題を示すことである.具体的には,プラクティス・ターンに基づいたSAPの観点から実践が組織や戦略を導く側面,特に非営利性の高い活動が習慣化され,正統化され,そして営利性の高い戦略が制度化されていく過程に照射する研究展開の必要性を示した.
  • ―ヒューム・パース・コモンズ・ケインズの慣習論―
    柴田 德太郎
    経済学論集
    2012年 77 巻 4 号 98-119
    発行日: 2012/01/01
    公開日: 2024/04/10
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 野尻 亘
    人文地理
    2013年 65 巻 5 号 397-417
    発行日: 2013年
    公開日: 2018/01/26
    ジャーナル フリー

    Recently, evolutionary economic geography has gained popularity in the field of economic geography in the West. Evolutionary economic geography deals with changes in the economic landscape through time via the concept of ‘routine,’ which is equivalent to a ‘genome’ in corporations.

    Evolutionary economic geography has been inspired by the process of regional growth and innovation in the context of evolutionary economics. The evolutionary component of economic geography is based on concepts such as contingency, lock-in by increasing returns, and network externality from path-dependency theory; variation, selection, and retention stemming from Generalized Darwinism; and emergence, panarchy, resilience, and the adaptive cycle model from complexity theory.

    The evolutionary theory of modern biology was not adopted without qualification in evolutionary economic geography. Instead, Generalized Darwinism was adopted as its ontology. For instance, the Lamarckian approach of acquired characteristics, in which genetic features are acquired as an adaptation of the individual’s post-birth environment and passed down to future generations, has been completely rejected in modern biology since the time of Darwin. However, in evolutionary economics, there is a view that a company constitutes ‘routines’ as part of the process of adaptation to its environment subsequent to its formation; this concept is closely akin to the Lamarckian methodology rejected in biology. The wide gap between biology and this methodology is highly significant. Genes are likened to routines, while companies are likened to populations, leading to the application of concepts such as panarchy and resilience, which in turn grew out of the concepts of ecosystem and succession, respectively.

    The development of biological methodology in economic geography grew out of criticism of the equilibrium concept of physical and mechanistic viewpoints in neoclassical economics. Alternatively, the concepts of restricted rationality, multiple equilibrium, irreversibility, increasing return, and self-organization are employed. Accordingly, corporate behaviors such as entry, development, and withdrawal in the market are viewed as selection and variation required for the adaptation of “routines” to market environment conditions. As a result of spinoffs and knowledge spillover, characterized by path dependence or contingency, cluster accumulation and network building take place.

    These basic routines play an important part in organizations at the corporate level, and also impact cities and regions. There is a need to consider emergence at the macro-structure level in relation to the impact of low-level processes, and also the relationship of broad-based social structure and embeddedness. In adjusting the structures of complicated processes of production, distribution, and consumption in the global landscape, global production networks, the spatial division of labor, and institutional arguments at the national and regional level facilitate individual company strategies and industrial dynamism. In addition, evolutionary economic geography must avoid fixed concepts of path dependence or lock-in.

    To achieve this, we need to prioritize location and region from a broader view of the spatial division of labor. We need to pay serious attention to the role of authority and policies in structuring economic organizations. In addition, understanding of the global socioeconomic structure in the national and socioeconomic context is required. Theories on the diversification of national and global institutions seem likely to be an important theme in evolutionary economic geography in the future.

  • 島本 実
    組織科学
    2015年 49 巻 2 号 40-52
    発行日: 2015/12/20
    公開日: 2016/06/29
    ジャーナル フリー
     本論文の課題は,なぜチャンドラーの学説が20世紀後半に経営史のみならず経営学に大きな影響を与えたかを明らかにすることにある.結論を先取りするなら,チャンドラーの歴史研究は,複数の個別事例の比較を通じて,背後にある一般的構造を発見するものであった.その視点はこれまで大量かつ多様なものの流れを実現する大企業に向けられてきたが,今後はより柔軟に流れを管理する新しい組織形態の研究が重要になるだろう.
  • ― ユトレヒト学派の実証研究を中心に ―
    水野 真彦
    経済地理学年報
    2019年 65 巻 3 号 239-259
    発行日: 2019/09/30
    公開日: 2020/09/30
    ジャーナル フリー

        本稿の目的は,進化経済地理学のなかでもユトレヒト学派による実証研究に焦点を絞り,産業集積とネットワークについての議論を展望し,これまでの経済地理学と比較することで,それぞれの長所と課題を検討することにある.第一に,スピンオフによって産業集積の形成を捉える議論を検討した.集積の形成は,集積の利益を求めた合理的な立地行動というより,スピンオフは母体企業の近隣への立地が多く,優れた能力やルーティンを受け継いだそれらのスピンオフが生き残ることによって説明できるとされる.また,集積の利益の中身は,集積の発展段階によって異なるとされている.第二に,制度的経済地理学による定性的な研究は,ユトレヒト学派の定量的分析が見落とした要素を描くことができるという利点がある一方で,制度の変化・進化の考察はついては課題が残されていることを論じた.経済地理学の多元性は,進化的/制度的あるいは定量的/定性的アプローチの対話によって新たな視点を生む可能性をもっている.第三に,ネットワークの形成と発展を進化プロセスとして捉える議論を整理した.集積におけるネットワークは不均等であり,知識はすべての企業に均しくいきわたるわけではないとされる.また,ネットワークにおけるつながりの形成要因は,地理的なものと社会ネットワーク的なものがあり,それらの相互関係のもとでネットワークは形成・発展していくことが示されている.

  • 二荒 麟
    三菱経済研究所 経済研究書
    2023年 2023 巻 148 号 1-79
    発行日: 2023/03/30
    公開日: 2024/03/01
    研究報告書・技術報告書 フリー
feedback
Top