詳細検索結果
以下の条件での結果を表示する: 検索条件を変更
クエリ検索: "フラン" 通貨
4,519件中 1-20の結果を表示しています
  • 正木 響
    アフリカレポート
    2024年 62 巻 15-22
    発行日: 2024/02/22
    公開日: 2024/02/22
    ジャーナル フリー HTML
  • マスワナ ジャンクロード
    アフリカ研究
    2002年 2002 巻 61 号 21-37
    発行日: 2002/12/20
    公開日: 2010/07/01
    ジャーナル フリー
    アフリカ
    通貨
    統合プロジェクトは, 共通の
    通貨
    による経済成長と資本統合を目的として, 2001年7月11日のアフリカ連合創立と共に打ち上げられた。本稿は最初に, アフリカは地域統合スキームにおいて最多でありながら, CFA
    フラン通貨
    地域だけが有益な金融・財政政策統合に成功している事実を考察する。次に,
    通貨
    統合についての議論を概観し, アフリカが効果的な
    通貨
    統合を達成するための条件についての議論を展開する。そして, アフリカ
    通貨
    統合が現在のCFA
    フラン通貨
    スキームの拡大により可能になるのかについて検討する。最後に, 低い大陸内貿易率に関わる障害を取り除くため, そして経済構造の脆弱さを改善するために, この
    通貨
    統合プロジェクトが (1) 段階的な地域
    通貨
    グループの推進, (2) 漸進的な政策協調により, 今後前進していくことを提案する。
  • 岡田 昭男
    国際経済
    1992年 1992 巻 43 号 144-147
    発行日: 1992/10/01
    公開日: 2010/07/07
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 正木 響
    アフリカ研究
    1997年 1997 巻 50 号 29-51
    発行日: 1997/03/31
    公開日: 2010/04/30
    ジャーナル フリー
    Sur le continent Africain, il existe deux monnaies communes à 13 pays dont 12 étaient les anciennes colonies de la France. Il s'agit du Franc CFA (le Franc Communauté Financière Africaine quant en l'Afrique de l'Ouest et le Franc Coopération Financière en Afrique Centrale) qui est lié au Franc Français par la parité fixe. Ces deux zones ayant les monnaies patrimoniales ont progressivement envisagé le libre èchange et la libre circulation des facteurs des productions dans ces zones intérieures.
    La possession d'une monnaie unique au sein des pays ayant des décalages conjoncturels est favorable à certain pays et défavorable à d'autres. D'un côté, elle leur permet de diminuer les coûts de transaction dans la zone intérieure et de faire avancer l'intégration régionale; d'un autre côté, elle leur empêche d'intervenir individuellement sur leur politique monétaire. En plus, il est douteux que cette union monétaire remplirait les conditions de la théorie des zones monétaires optimales.
    La monnaie du Franc CFA avait tendance à être surévaluée à cause de la politique du Franc fort depuis l'année 1985 ce qui était très éloignée de la situation des pays africains. La Banque Mondiale et le FMI insistaient sur une dévaluation du Franc CFA par rapport au Franc français comme une condition des programmes d'ajustement structurel et la France a osé le dévaluer en dépit de ses inquiétudes. Etant donné que seulement deux ans et demi se sont écoulés depuis la dévaluation du Franc CFA en 1994, ce travail montre les effets observés à court et moyen terme de la dévaluation dans les pays de l'UEMOA. Il est à noter que cette dévaluation a donné l'occasion de réviser fondamentalement le système de la zone Franc qui fut construct pendant l'époque coloniale par la France et aussi la relation paternaliste entre les pays africains et la France.
    Suite à l'indépendance, les pays de ce continent noir auraient eu intérêt à s'intégrer régionalement par stratégie économique visant un développement puissant comme la OUA. L'autre intégration régionale de l'Afrique de l'Ouest comportant les pays africains non seulement francophones mais aussi anglophones, CEDEAO, envisage d'avoir la monnaie unique avant l'an 2000; quant à l'OUA, un marché commun dans toute l'Afrique avant l'année 2025. Mais, it existe certaines inquiètudes pour l'intégration économique parmi les pays en voie de développement.
  • 独仏金融サービス市場における規制・監督・競争政策を事例に
    山村 延郎, 三田村 智
    日本EU学会年報
    2006年 2006 巻 26 号 260-284,437
    発行日: 2006/09/30
    公開日: 2010/05/21
    ジャーナル フリー
    The EEC's first banking directive (77/780/EEC) established the authorization system for credit institutions in each member state in 1977. Twelve years later, the single authorization system and the home country control were adopted through the second banking directive (89/646/EEC). In the financial services sector, the integration of a single market has made great strides forward.
    The universal banking model which the EU adopted came from the German banking system, however such a system had never existed in France until 1984. The German banking system has served as a basis for the regulatory structure of the common market of the EU. Under the influence of this system in neighboring countries, the French banking system underwent various reforms. The universal banking system was introduced by the Banking Act of 24 January 1984.
    In the 1990s, each member state liberalized their financial services markets and brought on competition in an open-market system under a single currency, the euro. The regulatory harmonization of the EU financial services market was further brought to fruition via the Financial Services Action Plan (FSAP).
    Despite freer competition and many examples of state enterprises being privatized, there still appears to be low competition from outside players in each domestic market, which is confirmed by an EU Commission report which showed that cross-border M & A activity is still very low.
    This report suggests that measures up to now, such as single-nationality or regulatory harmonization may not be enough to spur cross-border competition. Further policies that encourage freer competition across the EU may be needed. For example, one area in need of improvement may be changing policies that continue to allow local governments to protect and favor their regions' public or legal institutions. Private institutions have long protested against such protectionism.
    In Germany, as a result, the guarantees for the saving banks (Sparkasse) and its central institutions (Landesbank) from their public owner were abolished in July of 2005. In France some parts of the largest state-owned credit institution, CDC, were separated and privatized, leading the savings bank division, known as Caisses d'épargne, to be spun out as a cooperative bank.
    From the viewpoint of the traditional German economic model, which is known as “Soziale Marktwirtschaft” (social market economy), the privatization of state-owned institutions might be interpreted as the demise of Germany's long-held social market economy. However, there is still great inheritance in many of the EU member countries under such privatization moves. These cases on Germany and France in EU give some suggestions to the recent economic policies in Japan under the globalization.
  • 岡田 照男
    国際経済
    2000年 2000 巻 51 号 66-68
    発行日: 2000/06/20
    公開日: 2010/07/07
    ジャーナル フリー
  • ケインズ主義の受容過程
    廣田 功
    経済学史学会年報
    1997年 35 巻 35 号 15-27
    発行日: 1997年
    公開日: 2010/08/05
    ジャーナル フリー
    This considers the evolution of economic ideas in France before and after the Second World War, relating it to the reception of Keynesianism. In France, criticism of the “Laissez-Faire” and of Liberalism was primarily made not by university economists but by planist and économiste-ingénieur who professed the ideas of Economie Dirigée (Managed Economy). In this period, small groups espousing Keynesian principles emerged among them. As a result, the theoretical debate was less important and the main aspect of the reception was rather practical.
    They were concerned with the American New Deal, and under its influence, supported the financial and fiscal policy, devaluation and public works by a deficit spending, to stimulate the recovery until “Blum Experiment”. With the fall of the Blum cabinet, they were more concerned by the relative retardation in technologie and productive equipment which caused low supply capacity of French industry.
    The defeat against Germany in 1940 accelerated the consciousness of economic retardation. Many leaders, conscious of a crisis of National Power, accepted Keynesianism as means for achieving a Managed Economy. During the War, leaders of the Resistance and Vichy officials introduced Keynesianism as means to the Planning. The Monnet Plan formulated after the War was strengthened in this way, while in France Keynesianism inspired supply-side actions and basis for economic modernization.
  • アフリカの研究
    梅津 和郎
    国際政治
    1962年 1962 巻 18 号 62-70
    発行日: 1962/03/01
    公開日: 2010/09/01
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 岡田 昭男
    国際経済
    1984年 1984 巻 35 号 165-171
    発行日: 1984/09/21
    公開日: 2010/07/07
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 岩城 剛
    アフリカ研究
    1997年 1997 巻 51 号 85-87
    発行日: 1997/12/15
    公開日: 2010/04/30
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 岡田 昭男
    国際経済
    1996年 1996 巻 47 号 97-99
    発行日: 1996/09/09
    公開日: 2010/07/07
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 西村 茂
    年報政治学
    1993年 44 巻 71-88
    発行日: 1993/12/22
    公開日: 2009/12/21
    ジャーナル フリー
  • 矢後 和彦
    土地制度史学
    1987年 29 巻 3 号 23-37
    発行日: 1987/04/20
    公開日: 2017/11/30
    ジャーナル フリー
    This paper is a historical analysis of the currency crisis in 1920's France in its relation to the completion of "Le franc Poincare". The franc depreciation right after the World War I appeared in compound relation to the triple critical situation of the post-war French economy : inflation, trade balance deficit, and financial difficulty. This relation was reorganized through the restoration process from the economic crisis in 1920, and then the currency crisis was directly connected to the financial difficulty. During the process, industrial firms gained export premium, and commercial banks were forming monetary circuit by rediscounting of the accepted government bonds. Early in 1924, the exchange rate of the franc sharply failed. In the socio-economic critical situation, the Cartel des Gauches won the election in May 1924. The Cartel des Gauches administration tried several political measures against the currency crisis such as foundation of capital levy and consolidation of the floating debts. However, heading to the collapse of the administration, the government bond issue which was then the only possible political choice, faced a severe difficulty. In July 1926, after the collapse of the second Herriot cabinet, Poincare was inaugurated the prime minister, and the franc stabilization was set about. In the final phase of the currency crisis, industrial firms and commercial banks had changed their tactics from "anti-inflation" to "the approval of inflation". The financial difficulty and the recession in the summer of 1926 were the background of their decision. "Le franc Poincare" was a result of the inflationist decision.
  • ルイ・
    フラン
    ソワ デゥシェーヌ
    日本・EC研究者大会
    1976年 1976 巻 1 号 4-19
    発行日: 1976年
    公開日: 2010/04/15
    ジャーナル フリー
  • ――欧州統合と大西洋協力の模索――
    工藤 芽衣
    国際政治
    2021年 2021 巻 202 号 202_61-202_76
    発行日: 2021/03/29
    公開日: 2022/03/31
    ジャーナル フリー

    The purpose of this article is to describe international order designed by French neoliberalism through European integration and Atlanticism and its effects on the French government’s external policies.

    French neoliberalism was born in the late 1930s in the struggle to retrieve the credibility of liberal economy and fight against fascism and communism by searching for a third way. In most of the literature, the birth of new economic norms and new economic policy in the 1930s is explained by the emergence of Keynesian economics and economic policies, and ‘neo-liberalism’ is often placed as a contrasting concept to Keynesian policies. However, the original neoliberalism was, like Keynesian ideas, more socially oriented. After the Second World war, French neoliberals gradually lost common ground regarding economic principles, dividing between the left (neoliberals seeking a way to reconcile liberalism and socialists) and the right (trying to return to orthodox liberal economics). However, the two groups were still united as long as it concerned European integration and Atlanticism. These two ideas on the international order maintained the unity of the French neoliberalism from its birth to after the Second World War.

    With regard to the European integration, its support was based on the expectation that European integration become a framework to establish an ‘institutional market’ in which liberal competition was coordinated by the rules and interventions by the international institutions.

    The institutional market come to reality when the EEC was established in 1957 by the initiatives of the neoliberals. Not only did they develop a campaign for the Rome Treaty, they also desired for the French economy to really participate in the liberalisation processes in Europe with financial reform to contain inflation – which was finally achieved in the Rueff Plan in 1958.

    The influence of the Atlanticism of the neoliberals to the French external policy was limited. In 1936, when the Popular Front government adopted the devaluation of the franc as suggested by the neoliberals in the Tripatite Agreement between France, United States, and United Kingdom, this situation represented as a French decision to unite with liberal countries, denying fascism. However it was too late and the changing international circumstances made it meaningless.

    In the 1960s, the neoliberal’s Atlanticism was reflected in their critiques to the international monetary system centered on US dollars. Their critical attitude to the dollar did not mean their support for Atlanticism was lost, rather, they tried to consolidate the economic basis of the Atlantic cooperation by reforming the international monetary system. However, when their call for return to the gold standard was adopted by the General de Gaulle, it was used as a tool to attack Atlanticism.

  • 正木 響
    アフリカレポート
    2019年 57 巻 87-92
    発行日: 2019/10/29
    公開日: 2019/10/29
    ジャーナル フリー HTML
  • 畑山 敏夫
    平和研究
    2021年 55 巻 39-59
    発行日: 2021年
    公開日: 2023/11/24
    ジャーナル フリー

    Since the creation, of the nation state, each nation has entrusted its life and peace to elected governments.

    When a government initiates a war, the lives and fortunes of the nation are sacrificed on the pretext that it is beneficial to the nation. Since the end of the Second World War, and out of this regretful situation, the benefits of the nation state have been realized, guaranteeing the economic and social development of the nation.

    In the 1980s, as globalization gained momentum, nation states could no longer guarantee economic prosperity and social stability. Numerous difficulties began to emerge, including higher unemployment, an increase in non-regular employment, the decline of local industries, and increasing numbers of immigrants and refugees. Governments were no longer able to solve these problems alone.

    European nation states sought to conquer these difficulties by creating a supranational union of European countries. However, this did not lead to revolutionary achievements, leading to an increase in frustration and distrust of the supranational organization by the individual states. As a result, certain states now prefer to enjoy their profits and deal with their security issues at the nation state level, once again.

    This paper focuses on the political phenomenon of “re-nationalization.”

  • ―発生,深化・拡大,救出―
    長部 重康
    日本EU学会年報
    2014年 2014 巻 34 号 99-127
    発行日: 2014/06/15
    公開日: 2016/06/15
    ジャーナル フリー
    The author examines the European sovreign debt crisis from an economic point of view, clarifying its structural causes, expansion process and bailout package.
    The main focus is on snch questions as: Why did the euro crisis break out long after the global financial crisis rooted in American financial market erros? What are specific differences between these two crises? What was the main structural cause that has given rise to the euro crisis? If it was heterogeneity between southern eurozone countries and northern ones, what has brought about this North-South divide? Why has the crisis been intensified and prolonged so far beyond all expectations? Why have austerity measures been inevitably adopted by all eurozone countries as the golden rule forced by Germany? Who are the main saviors of the euro system?
    Speculation about the breakup of the eurozone hastened member countries to implement such ambitious governance reforms that they couldn’t be commonly accepted. The new triangle of the Monetary Union illustrates the following institutional set-up. The responsibility for price stability lies with the ECB; the responsibility for fiscal sustainability lies with individual governments under joint oversight; financial stability is both an individual and a collective responsibility of government; and the safety net of the EFSF/ESM covers the triangle firmly.
  • 尾立 要子
    島嶼研究
    2002年 2002 巻 3 号 67-90
    発行日: 2002年
    公開日: 2010/04/30
    ジャーナル フリー
  • ―北欧・JAK銀行とスイス・WIR銀行―
    泉 留維
    ノンプロフィット・レビュー
    2001年 1 巻 1 号 79-90
    発行日: 2001年
    公開日: 2001/10/17
    ジャーナル フリー
    本稿は,オルタナティブ・バンキングの歴史とその意義を明確にしようとしたものである.オルタナティブ・バンキングは,貨幣の貯蔵機能を減退させ,より貨幣が社会の中で循環するように,預金は基本的にゼロ利子等の特徴を持ったものである.今回は,その事例として,北欧のJAK銀行とスイスのWIR銀行を取り上げる.両銀行とも1929年から始まる世界大恐慌の中で生み出されたものであり,シルビオ・ゲゼルが創出した自由貨幣論を理念の中心に置いている.無利子貯蓄-貸付銀行であるJAK銀行は,デンマークで1931年に,スウェーデンで1965年に設立された.中小企業のための銀行であるWIR銀行は,1934年に設立された.土地に根付く中小企業や人々の活性化の潜在的な可能性を引き出すものとしてのオルタナティブ・バンキングは,主としてインフォーマルな経済を活性化させる地域
    通貨
    と並んで,地域コミュニティにおいて注目すべき存在である.
feedback
Top